Estimation of a Symmetric Normalized Quadratic (SNQ) Profit function.
snqProfitEst( priceNames, quantNames, fixNames =NULL, instNames =NULL, data, form =0, base =1, scalingFactors =NULL, weights = snqProfitWeights( priceNames, quantNames, data,"DW92", base = base ), method = ifelse( is.null( instNames ),"SUR","3SLS"),...)
Arguments
priceNames: a vector of strings containing the names of netput prices.
quantNames: a vector of strings containing the names of netput quantities (inputs must be negative).
fixNames: an optional vector of strings containing the names of the quantities of (quasi-)fixed inputs.
instNames: an optional vector of strings containing the names of instrumental variables (for 3SLS estimation).
data: a data frame containing the data.
form: the functional form to be estimated (see details).
base: the base period(s) for scaling prices (see details). If argument weights is not specified, argument base is also used to obtain the weights for normalizing prices (see snqProfitWeights).
scalingFactors: a vector of factors to scale prices (see details).
weights: a vector of weights for normalizing prices.
method: the estimation method (passed to systemfit).
...: arguments passed to systemfit
Details
The Symmetric Normalized Quadratic (SNQ) profit function is defined as follows (this functional form is used if argument form equals 0):
with π = profit, pi = netput prices, zi = quantities of fixed inputs, w=∑i=1nθipi = price index for normalization, θi = weights of prices for normalization, and αi, βij, δij and γij = coefficients to be estimated.
The netput equations (output supply in input demand) can be obtained by Hotelling's Lemma (qi=∂π/∂pi):
In my experience the fit of the model is sometimes not very good, because the effect of the fixed inputs is forced to be proportional to the weights for price normalization θi. In this cases I use following extended SNQ profit function (this functional form is used if argument form equals 1):
Argument scalingFactors can be used to scale prices, e.g. for improving the numerical stability of the estimation (e.g. if prices are very large or very small numbers) or for assessing the robustness of the results when changing the units of measurement. The prices are multiplied by the scaling factors, while the quantities are divided my the scaling factors so that the monetary values of the inputs and outputs and thus, the profit, remains unchanged. If argument scalingFactors is NULL, argument base is used to automatically obtain scaling factors so that the scaled prices are unity in the base period or - if there is more than one base period - that the means of the scaled prices over the base periods are unity. Argument base can be either
(a) a single number: the row number of the base prices,
(b) a vector indicating several observations: The means of these observations are used as base prices,
(c) a logical vector with length equal to the number of rows of the data set that is specified by argument data: The means of the observations indicated as 'TRUE' are used as base prices, or
(d) NULL: prices are not scaled. If argument base is NULL, argument weights must be specified, because the weights cannot be calculated if the base period is not specified. An alternative way to use unscaled prices is to set argument scalingFactors equal to a vector of ones (see examples below).
If the scaling factors are explicitly specified by argument scalingFactors, argument base is not used for obtaining scaling factors (but it is used for obtaining weights if argument weights is not specified).
Returns
a list of class snqProfitEst containing following objects: - coef: a list containing the vectors/matrix of the estimated coefficients:
* alpha = $\alpha_i$.
* beta = $\beta_{ij}$.
* delta = $\delta_{ij}$ (only if quasi-fix inputs are present).
* gamma = $\gamma_{ij}$ (only if quasi-fix inputs are present).
* allCoef = vector of all coefficients.
* allCoefCov = covariance matrix of all coefficients.
* stats = all coefficients with standard errors, t-values and p-values.
* liCoef = vector of linear independent coefficients.
* liCoefCov = covariance matrix of linear independent coefficients.
ela: a list of class snqProfitEla that contains (amongst others) the price elasticities at mean prices and mean quantities (see snqProfitEla).
fixEla: matrix of the fixed factor elasticities at mean prices and mean quantities.
hessian: hessian matrix of the profit function with respect to prices evaluated at mean prices.
convexity: logical. Convexity of the profit function.
r2: R2-values of all netput equations.
est: estimation results returned by systemfit.
weights: the weights of prices used for normalization.
normPrice: vector used for normalization of prices.
data: data frame of originally supplied data.
fitted: data frame that contains the fitted netput quantities and the fitted profit.
pMeans: means of the scaled netput prices.
qMeans: means of the scaled netput quantities.
fMeans: means of the (quasi-)fixed input quantities.
priceNames: a vector of strings containing the names of netput prices.
quantNames: a vector of strings containing the names of netput quantities (inputs must be negative).
fixNames: an optional vector of strings containing the names of the quantities of (quasi-)fixed inputs.
instNames: an optional vector of strings containing the names of instrumental variables (for 3SLS estimation).
form: the functional form (see details).
base: the base period(s) for scaling prices (see details).
weights: vector of weights of the prices for normalization.
scalingFactors: factors to scale prices (and quantities).
method: the estimation method.
References
Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales (1987) Flexible functional forms and global curvature conditions. Econometrica, 55, p. 43-68.
Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales (1992) Quadratic Spline Models for Producer's Supply and Demand Functions. International Economic Review, 33, p. 705-722.
Kohli, U.R. (1993) A symmetric normalized quadratic GNP function and the US demand for imports and supply of exports. International Economic Review, 34, p. 243-255.
See Also
snqProfitEla and snqProfitWeights.
Author(s)
Arne Henningsen
Examples
if( requireNamespace('micEcon', quietly =TRUE)){ data( germanFarms, package ="micEcon") germanFarms$qOutput <- germanFarms$vOutput / germanFarms$pOutput
germanFarms$qVarInput <--germanFarms$vVarInput / germanFarms$pVarInput
germanFarms$qLabor <--germanFarms$qLabor
priceNames <- c("pOutput","pVarInput","pLabor") quantNames <- c("qOutput","qVarInput","qLabor") estResult <- snqProfitEst( priceNames, quantNames,"land", data = germanFarms ) estResult$ela # Oh, that looks bad!# it it reasonable to account for technological progress germanFarms$time <- c(0:19) estResult2 <- snqProfitEst( priceNames, quantNames, c("land","time"), data = germanFarms ) estResult2$ela # Ah, that looks better!# estimation with unscaled prices estResultNoScale <- snqProfitEst( priceNames, quantNames, c("land","time"), data = germanFarms, scalingFactors = rep(1,3)) print( estResultNoScale )# alternative way of estimation with unscaled prices estResultNoScale2 <- snqProfitEst( priceNames, quantNames, c("land","time"), data = germanFarms, base =NULL, weights = snqProfitWeights( priceNames, quantNames, germanFarms )) all.equal( estResultNoScale[-20], estResultNoScale2[])# please note that the SNQ Profit function is not invariant# to units of measurement so that different scaling factors # result in different estimates of elasticities: all.equal( estResult2$ela, estResultNoScale$ela )}